How to fix Britain’s barmy VAT regime

453     0
How to fix Britain’s barmy VAT regime
How to fix Britain’s barmy VAT regime

Britain’s second-most-important tax is riddled with holes

Biscuits are tricky tax terrain. One way they can fall foul of Britain’s value-added tax (vat), a consumption levy, is to have an overindulgent chocolate coating. But how much is too much? A McVitie’s chocolate digestive faces 20% vat, a conventional one 0%. A chocolate-chip cookie is safe. So is a gingerbread man, so long as he has chocolate only in dots for his eyes. Add any more and he is taxed at 20%.

Keep digging and the perversity continues. Children’s clothes, newspapers (including this one), cruises, solar-panel installations, bicycle helmets, coffins and sports lessons all also sidestep vat.

 tdiqrididtqinv

VAT is one of Britain’s most important taxes, raising £168bn ($208bn; 0.7% of gdp) last year; only income taxes bring in more. It is also full of holes. Britain has more reliefs from vat than almost any other rich country (see chart 1). The explicit carve-outs are worth more than £70bn annually, according to hmrc, the tax-collecting agency (see chart 2). Reducing them to the rich-world average would raise around £40bn in additional revenue. The Labour Party wants to put vat on private-school fees, raising a net amount of around £1.3bn-1.5bn. But such tweaking is not nearly ambitious enough.

There are two common rationales for vat exemptions. The first is fairness: the poor tend to spend more of their income than the wealthy do, making vat inherently regressive. But the best way to counterbalance the regressive nature of vat is not to selectively exclude items but to make the remainder of the tax and welfare system more progressive. Exclusions are bound to be poorly targeted: the rich will benefit more in cash terms from carve-outs on clothes and food.

If these savings reach consumers at all. Researchers at the imf found that under a third of the savings from product-specific vat reductions in Europe were passed on to households; retailers and producers pocketed the remainder. Cuts to the overall vat rate—a much more visible change—were passed on in full.

The second rationale is to pursue social goals: the state should encourage spending with positive spillovers, like schooling, books or bicycle helmets. The economic logic here is more defensible. There are plenty of cases where the benefits of some spending are not fully felt by the buyer: rooftop solar panels contribute to a greener power supply, for example.

But jamming such aims into the vat rules is a bad idea. Subsidies should be specific, targeted and justified on their own terms. Instead endless efforts are made to expand carve-outs. Campaigns are running to exclude sunscreen, bras, dog food, hotels, toilet rolls, home makeovers, pubs, audiobooks, defibrillators and haircuts. Some are well-intentioned; others are cash grabs. Their effect is to skew spending and force up other taxes.

Some exemptions are genuinely difficult to eliminate. One is relief for small businesses: tracking vat is an administrative hassle, so most countries do have good reason to let off the tiddliest firms. But Britain’s turnover threshold of £90,000 a year is too high—the average in the eu is around £35,000—and deters firms from expanding beyond that mark.

The knottiest problem is “structural reliefs”, which are embedded in how the tax is set up rather than being deliberate carve-outs. Take financial services: firms tend to bundle their fees in with the interest rates they charge. That makes it harder to isolate and tax those charges. Structuring vat in areas like insurance and gambling is also fiddly, but not insoluble. Some countries, like New Zealand, manage to levy the tax on a much wider base.

Politics is a more daunting barrier to vat reform. The last chancellor of the exchequer to seriously tangle with vat was George Osborne. In 2012 he tried to extend the levy to all hot takeaway foods; tabloids promptly christened it the “pasty tax” and he was eventually forced to climb down.

His mistake was to succumb to the piecemeal logic of vat exemptions. Tackling a single exemption focuses the debate on the product. Occasionally, that can be to politicians’ advantage: Labour’s plans for private schools are popular. But people generally like the things they buy and dislike spending more on them.

Wholesale vat reform would focus the conversation on the overall tax system. Some grumbling would be inevitable: there would doubtless be headlines about “coffin taxes” and “zoo levies”. But if tax increases were wholly or partly offset by a cut to the standard 20% rate of vat and by more generous benefits for the poorest people, that would clean up Britain’s tax system, encourage firms to grow and shut the cottage industry of lobbyists clamouring for exemptions. The prize would be worth more than a few crumbs.

Thomas Brown

Economics, VAT, Britain

Read more similar news:

31.07.2023, 12:17 • Finance
Cost of taxi journeys could rise by 20% as Uber wins major high court battle
21.08.2023, 11:03 • Finance
Tesco makes major change in stores from today to help save Brits money
28.08.2023, 09:50 • Finance
Waitrose follows M&S and Tesco by making major change across all stores
10.10.2023, 08:28 • News
Woman raises funds to buy defibrillator for pensioners but is hit with £240 VAT
26.11.2023, 09:00 • News
Campaigner celebrates as 'period pants' will be exempt from VAT from January 1st
20.02.2024, 12:49 • News
Eight in 10 Brits deem toilet roll 'essential' - but government charge VAT on it
07.05.2024, 21:33 • News
Prominent Conservative property expert slapped with £4.5 million tax bill for construction dubbed ’Ten Floors of Whores’
17.05.2024, 20:05 • World
Italian authorities bust VAT fraud ring
09.06.2024, 06:52 • News
Labour to promise a ’triple lock’ commitment with no increases in the ’big three’ taxes
08.07.2024, 15:26 • News
Andrew Tate and his brother are accused of ’never paying a penny’ in tax on the £21m they made online